The Behavioral
Implications
The range of behavioral
options in the virtual economy was broad. The ability to
use nonmonetary mechanisms to pay taxes to governments
and bills to the natural monopolies fundamentally
changed the range of opportunities for action available
to Russian enterprise directors. By allowing enterprises
to settle their obligations by delivering goods for
which there was no effective demand, the governments and
the monopolies offered an incentive to avoid
restructuring. For many enterprises it was easier to
produce such goods than to restructure and earn
additional monetary income to pay bills in cash.
Producing those goods allowed for use of idle capital
and labor. In short, offsets and barter permitted some
enterprises to survive without restructuring. To
represent the full range of choice, not only
market-oriented activity but also behavior
characteristic of the virtual economy, Gaddy and Ickes
(2002) employed the notion of a two-dimensional space,
called r-d space. The following sections outline
their model.
|
|
|
|
Liberalization
revealed the distance
that a Russian
enterprise would have
to travel to compete
in the world
economy.  |
|
|
|
|
|
Market Distance, d
The impact of liberalization
on the Soviet economy can be expressed with a spatial
metaphor: liberalization revealed the distance that a
Russian enterprise would have to travel to compete in
the world economy. Let d designate the
enterprise’s “distance to the market” at the start of
transition. Clearly, d depends on the
enterprise’s initial endowments of the things that
matter for market viability: physical and human capital,
as well as the enterprise’s marketing structure and
organizational behavior, but also the characteristics of
the good that the enterprise produces (its quality and
cost of production). Formally, define an enterprise’s
d as the amount of capital expenditure needed to
enable the enterprise to produce a product that is
competitive in the market. The fundamental reason for
measuring d in terms of the investment cost is
that transition causes a divergence between the value of
existing (inherited) capital and that of newly installed
capital.
One may begin to grasp this
point by recalling what happened to traditional models
of investment in market economies during the energy
crisis of the 1970s. Those models predicted that
investment would decline, given the tremendous increase
in the price of energy. In fact, however, spending on
new equipment and buildings soared. The reason for this
discrepancy between model and reality was the divergence
between the value of installed capital that was energy
intensive and new capital that was energy saving. The
conventional model ignored the sharp decline in the
economic value of the existing capital stock as a result
of the 1973 energy crisis. Installed capital had been
the result of investment decisions based on low energy
prices; hence, its value fell dramatically once energy
prices quadrupled. This in turn only increased the
demand for new investment in energy-saving equipment.
The result was a divergence between the value of
installed capital (which lost value) and that of new
capital (which had full economic value). In the Russian
context, measuring market distance d by the need
for new capital investment is a way of capturing the
cost of filling the gap between the value of inherited
(Soviet) capital and new (market) capital.
Distribution of
d
The level of d
differs widely among enterprises in the economy. An
enterprise that already produces a product it can sell
in world markets at a price above cost will have a value
of d equal to 0. A completely noncompetitive
enterprise will have an enormously large d.
Everyone else will be somewhere between. For example, an
oil-producing enterprise will have a very low d.
Its product is already right for the market. It may need
only relatively small investments in marketing, and so
on. A Soviet-style machine tool producer, in contrast,
is likely to have a long distance to travel.
The distribution of
d’s in transition economies differs in two
respects from that in market economies. In transition
economies the range of d’s is greater and the
distribution is more skewed. Both differences stem from
the dissimilarity in the process of entry and exit in
market and planned economies. In a market economy,
whether or not a new firm attempts to enter an industry
depends on the founders’ expectations about the new
firm’s competitiveness. They will enter if they expect
the firm’s potential costs to be lower (its productivity
to be higher) than those of existing firms. No firm
enters an industry in which it expects it will be
noncompetitive. Over time the competitiveness of some
firms declines, so d increases. But if a firm in
a market economy has too high a level of d, it
will be forced to close. Competition and hard budget
constraints cause high-d enterprises to shut
down.
In a transition economy, in contrast, some enterprises
have very high d's that would not be observed in
a market economy. There are several reasons for these
high-d enterprises. First, in socialist
economies entry was not determined by expectations of
profitability or competitiveness but rather by the need
to fulfill plan targets. Second, insulation from the
world economy meant that enterprises were created that
produced goods for which the country might not have had
a comparative advantage. Third, especially in the case
of Russia, the priority given to defense production led
to a proliferation of enterprises that produced goods
whose market collapsed with the end of the Soviet
Union. Fourth, since the geographic location of
industry in the Soviet period was based on ignoring
transportation costs (as well as the costs associated
with extraordinarily cold temperatures), the location
of enterprises was also a factor in increasing the
d in many cases. For all of these reasons, the
distribution of the d’s in Russia at the onset
of the transition had a much higher mean and was more
skewed to the right than in a mature market economy.
This extra mass of high-d enterprises was the
burden of the Soviet legacy. And it was this burden
that was the essence of the restructuring problem: so
many enterprises had to all radically reduce their
distance to the market at the same time.
One way to think of the
purpose of economic reform is to reduce the average
distance in the economy. This occurs through three
means: (1) exit of high-d enterprises; (2) entry
of new low-d enterprises; (3) and reduction of
the d of surviving enterprises. In an ideal
market world, market distance would be the only
condition that characterized the state of an enterprise.
If the only important difference in enterprises were
their initial level of d, then policies that put
pressure on existing high-d enterprises and
encourage creation of new low-d enterprises would
have the effect of pushing the distribution in the
direction of the market.
|
|
|
|
Enterprise
directors relied
heavily on the
accumulation and use
of personal
connections.
Relational capital was
passed forward to the
post-Soviet system in
a deceptively simple
manner: it was
spontaneously
privatized.  |
|
|
|
|
|
Relational
Capital
The conventional view of
restructuring, that reform means reducing d,
assumes that each enterprise has one set of resources —
its physical and human capital — that it must use ever
more efficiently in order to survive. The virtual
economy view, in contrast, posits that some enterprises
have another resource, relational capital, which they
can draw on to enhance their chances for survival.
Relational capital is the stock of goodwill that an
enterprise can use to avoid the strictures of the budget
constraint. An enterprise that has high relational
capital can undertake transactions (bartering, using tax
offsets, delaying payment) that other enterprises, with
low amounts of relational capital, cannot get away with.
To put it another way, relational capital is goodwill
that can be translated into the ability to continue to
engage in production and exchange without reducing the
distance to the market. It is therefore the existence of
this second dimension that can explain the persistent
survival of high-d enterprises in the Russia of
the 1990s.
At the onset of transition
enterprises differed in their inherited relational
capital — call it r — just as they differed in
their d. Some enterprises (or their directors)
had very good relations with local and/or federal
officials. Relations with other enterprises also
varied.
Origins of Relational
Capital
The relational capital of
Russian enterprises was initially accumulated in the
Soviet system. Enterprise directors relied heavily on
the accumulation and use of personal connections.
Relational capital was passed forward to the post-Soviet
system in a deceptively simple manner: it was
spontaneously privatized. And here lies an important
aspect of economic transition in Russia. As Hewett
(1988) described, plan fulfillment in the Soviet economy
required enterprise directors to use informal skills.
Their ability to accomplish this, and their position in
the economic hierarchy, was critical to their incomes.
While directors earned income from these positions, they
did not legally own the source of these incomes. The
demise of the planning system, which had already begun
with Mikhail Gorbachev’s reforms in the late
perestroika period, had the effect of increasing
the autonomy of enterprise directors. With the start of
economic reform and privatization, the role of the
enterprise director increased; other mediating actors
(planners, party officials) played less and less of a
formal role in economic allocation. Directors used this
opportunity to appropriate the returns to the
relationships they had developed and cultivated under
the previous system. However, in order for directors to
appropriate these returns, the enterprises had to
continue to operate. Much of the relational capital was
both enterprise specific and person specific. To the
extent that it was enterprise specific, the director
could not cash out the relational capital. The primary
form of these connections was relationships with
directors of other enterprises, often in related lines
of activity, and with ministerial officials and local
government officials. The relational capital was
worthless to the incumbent director unless he remained
in that particular enterprise. He could not leave the
enterprise and take the relational capital with him.
Furthermore, because it was person specific, he could
not sell it to someone else. Instead, in order to
appropriate the rents accruing to his relational
capital, he had to remain in the enterprise and keep it
operating. The privatization of relational capital is
thus an important part of the explanation of why
directors fought to keep open enterprises that had few
prospects in the market economy.
back to
Articles
|