The roots of the virtual economy
lay in the structure and institutions bequeathed to Russia
by its Soviet predecessor. Some parts of the economy,
notably the resource industries, were value-adding. But most
of the vast manufacturing sector that Russia had inherited
could not compete in a market setting. In fact, by the final
years of the Soviet era, the manufacturing sector was in
poor condition even on the terms of the planned economy.
By official Soviet standards, more than one-third of
equipment in Russian industry was physically obsolete.
Soviet planning practice, which emphasized output over
costs, set physical, rather than economic, obsolescence as
the criterion for removing a machine from the factory. As
long as the machine could produce anything at all, it was
kept in production. The result was very low replacement
rates for capital equipment.
The location of industry in the
Soviet economy was another problem. Not only did Soviet
location policy ignore transportation costs but it also
failed to take into account the costs associated with the
cold Russian climate — in terms of energy use, health
maintenance, and many other factors. By being placed in some
of Russia’s coldest and most remote regions, the
manufacturing enterprises were rendered even less
competitive and less attractive for foreign investment.
Equally important as the
structure of the Soviet economy and its lack of
competitiveness was the fact that this reality was hidden.
As the market transition began, past history and performance
gave no information about which sectors, or enterprises,
were value-adding and which were value-destroying. The
culprit was distorted Soviet pricing.
Soviet Pricing and the
“Circus Mirror” Effect
Soviet prices were not based
on opportunity cost, or value; rather they were simply
an accounting instrument to measure plan fulfillment.
Although Soviet prices were set arbitrarily, they were
not set randomly. They were determined by specific rules
of the system, and this produced some systematic biases.
First, the planners underpriced raw material inputs,
especially energy. They based raw materials prices only
on the operating costs of extraction, while ignoring
rent. In so doing, they disregarded the opportunity cost
of using the resources now rather than in the
future.
|
|
|
|
Soviet
prices were not based
on opportunity cost,
or value; rather they
were simply an
accounting instrument
to measure plan
fulfillment.  |
|
|
|
|
|
The planners’ overriding goal was to increase today’s
output. Scarcity pricing might have induced more
conservation, but it would have militated against
maximizing current production. This bias in raw
materials prices fed into the system of industrial
prices. Heavy consumers of energy were, in effect,
subsidized. So, too, were heavy users of capital,
thanks to the absence of interest charges. In short,
costs of production were calculated on the basis of an
incomplete enumeration of costs. This led to lower
prices for inputs, especially resource inputs, than for
final uses and thus an understatement of the share of
gross output used in production and, hence, an
overstatement of net output.
In addition to incomplete
cost-based pricing, the Soviet system was explicitly
biased toward certain users. The Soviet leadership
assigned priority in the economy to heavy industry,
especially defense industry, and it was important that
it appear that these sectors were producing value. This
nonscarcity–based pricing was like a distorting mirror
at the carnival. It created the illusion that many
enterprises were value producing when in fact they were
value destroying.
The “Loot Chain”
A further factor
contributing to the opaqueness of the Soviet economy and
its post-Soviet successor was the way in which income
from control of assets was passed down as payoffs
through what Gregory Grossman (1998) referred to as the
loot chain. In the USSR, wealth diverted from the
official state economy into private hands was shared
among networks of individuals in the form of payoffs,
bribes, and other schemes. Over time an ever greater
proportion of people’s incomes depended on the chain of
corruption and side payments.
|
|
|
|
Basic ideas
of a market economy,
such as the
relationship between
individual effort and
reward, became almost
impossibly
obscure.  |
|
|
|
|
|
The virtual economy perpetuated the loot chain in
post-Soviet Russia. The living standards of a huge
number of people depended on the chain of production
and distribution of goods and services in the virtual
economy system. In the virtual economy, value
redistribution, in contrast to looting pure and simple,
occurred in a form that paralleled and was intertwined
with actual productive economic activity. This made it
especially difficult for agents to discern what their
own value and the value of their assets would have been
in a well-developed and transparent economy. Basic
ideas of a market economy, such as the relationship
between individual effort and reward, became almost
impossibly obscure. One’s static position in the
production process — for instance, membership in the
work force of a particular enterprise — was more
important for success than individual skills and
abilities. The Soviet system separated “what you get”
from “what you do.” The reality was that the
effort-reward nexus was random. Instead of “from each
according to his ability, to each according to his
needs (or ability),” it was “to each according to some
unknowable, random criterion.” The durability of the
misperception depended on its opaqueness. There was no
alternative, competing information about the real
relationship. This meant that the loot chain was also a
constraint on the future evolution of the economy.
Individuals were dependent on the prevailing system at
the same time that they could not know what an
alternative system would offer. The uncertainty caused
them to resist abandoning the prevailing system.
Impermissibility of True
Reform
While there was no accurate
information about the economic importance of the large
Soviet manufacturing sector, its social and political
importance was unavoidable. Many of the least
competitive enterprises — the so-called dinosaurs of
Soviet industry — were socially the most important. They
employed millions of workers and provided for tens of
millions of their family members. Entire cities depended
on them. The sheer size of this sector — as shown by
employment — operated to maintain its social and
political importance, and the illusion of its economic
performance. In a sense, then, the importance of the
manufacturing sector in Russia was an illusion
economically but continued to be a political and social
reality.
This latter reality
constrained serious market reform policies. Russia did
not formally reject the policies themselves; instead, it
continued with a pretense of market reform. Policymakers
launched one measure after another in their attempt to
transform Russia into a market economy. But very few of
those measures were allowed to play themselves out to
their full extent. The consequences of complete and
proper implementation would have been politically
intolerable. Thus, while the nation’s leadership
proclaimed reform policies, enterprises and other agents
continued to behave in ways that rendered the policies
ineffective.
back to
Articles